Occasionally, we will make reference to economic studies, but only to the extent
necessary to clarify some aspects of our analysis. It will suffice here to say that, in
the WTO arena, despite the lack of agreement among scholars and policy-makers
about its consequences, regionalism has been generally tolerated as an exception to
the Most Favoured Nation Clause (MFN) for two basic reasons: first, it is thought
to expand trade (in fact, the preamble to the Understanding on the Interpretation of
Article XXIV of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994 states that this
exception to MFN reflects a recognition by WTO Members of “the contribution to
the expansion of world trade that may be made by closer integration between the
economies of the parties to such agreements”.); and second, regional trade
agreements can serve as building blocks for further multilateral liberalization2.
Both arguments have been opposed3: nonetheless, it can be generally said that the
rationale for the discipline of preferential trade arrangements in the GATT
framework is that such arrangements are supposed to facilitate trade
liberalization among members, as well as lead governments to oppose
protectionism at both the regional and the multilateral levels4. After all, GATT
Article XXIV itself sets this principle out, by enunciating that the purpose of
regional trade agreements should be to facilitate trade between the constituent
territories, and not to raise barriers to trade of other GATT contracting parties
with such territories.
The “special relationship” between the ACP States and the EC is, for several
reasons, an interesting example of preferential trade regime.
It is evident at a glance that the purposes of such a regime go far beyond the
simple facilitation of trade between the parties, since among its objectives we
also find the economic development of ACP countries, their gradual inclusion
into the world economy, the promotion of human rights, democracy, rule of law.
2
See World Trade Report 2007, pp. 138
3
See, for instance, Sungjoon Cho, Defragmenting World Trade, Northwestern Journal of International
Law &Business, 27: 39 (2006), 39-88
4
Chad Damro, The Political Economy of Regional Trade Agreements, in Lorand Bartels and Federico
Ortino (editors) Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO Legal System, Oxford: Oxford University Press
(2006), p. 24
4
The EC aid and trade policy towards the ACP States, aimed at pursuing the
objectives we just sketched out, has been based for a long time on non-
reciprocity and discrimination against non-ACP developing countries.
As we will see later on in the dissertation, this profile of the ACP-EC trade
relationship was successfully challenged before the WTO Dispute Settlement
Body in many occasions. Thus, the ACP-EC trade relationship can be considered
a good example of how the WTO is coping with the question of the increasing
number of preferential schemes in force today. This is a serious matter, entailing
systemic problems that may affect the very foundations of the GATT/WTO legal
system, notably the most favoured nation clause and the principle of non-
discrimination5.
With a view to broaching the delicate subject of regional trade agreements, we
will outline, first and foremost, the current discipline of “regionalism”6 in the
WTO legal system, highlighting its strengths and weaknesses. This is indeed a
cross-cutting subject, since it touches many different aspects of the WTO law and
institutional machinery, from trade in goods to trade in services, from the way in
which WTO tackles the question of economic underdevelopment (and the one of
special and differential treatment for developing countries) to the role and
attributions of the Dispute Settlement Body; in this respect, particular attention
will be paid to the role of the DSB as regards the review (in terms of
GATT/WTO compatibility) of regional trade arrangements.
The actual functioning of the review mechanisms available within the WTO legal
framework will be illustrated in Chapters II and III, whose purpose is to show
how the problem of WTO inconsistency has evolved throughout the history of
the controversial trade relationship between the European Community and the
African, Caribbean and Pacific States.
5
On regional trade agreements as a “serious” (because of its permanent nature) exception to the MFN
clause see T.N Srinivasan, Nondiscrimination in GATT/WTO: was there anything to begin with and is
there anything left? World Trade Review (2005), 4: 1, 69–95
6
For a definition of regionalism to the purposes of this dissertation, see Chapter I Par. 1
5
In Chapter II, we will examine the trade regime established by the Lomé
Convention, that has disciplined such relationship for twenty-five years, focusing
in particular on the so-called “banana dispute”, which started in 1993 and whose
sequels stretch out to the days in which we are writing.
We will successively deal with the transition from the Lomé Convention to the
Partnership Agreement signed in Cotonou in 2000, and with the problems posed
by the strict timetable established by the seven-years waiver which was conceded
by the WTO members in order to facilitate such transition.
Our intention is to show how the issue of WTO compatibility has been, since
late 1990s, a top priority for the European Community, and how WTO
compatibility is actually dealt with by the Cotonou Partnership Agreement.
The main features of the Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs), which,
according to the Cotonou Partnership Agreement, should be the instruments to
project the ACP-EC relationship in the new century, by harmonizing it with the
multilateral rules currently in force, will be dealt with in Chapter III.
We will try to analyze, from both a formal and a substantial point of view, all the
problematic issues raised by these agreements, some of which have been already
initialled.
It is important to underscore that the EC-ACP relationship will be analyzed in its
trade-related aspects and that, as a consequence, the development dimension of
the relationship, despite its paramount importance, will not be the object of an in-
depth analysis.
However, it is also important to recall that, as well-known, the performance of
the ACP States in terms of trade expansion and economic growth since the
signature of the first Lomé Convention, in 1975, has been disappointing to say
the least, and that thirty-nine out of seventy-nine ACP States are currently
classified as least developed countries (LDC). Therefore, when considering the
new trade regime introduced by the EC towards its former colonies, we will need
to bear in mind that it is bound to have an important impact on the ACP States in
terms of economic development.
6
In this sense, we have asked ourselves a first question: is the path indicated by
the Cotonou Partnership agreement actually leading to a WTO-compatible trade
regime, though somehow preserving the “special” nature of the ACP-EC
relationship? The answer is probably “yes”, but, as will be made clear in Chapter
III, the problem with EPAs is that, if on the one hand they are likely to solve the
issues of WTO compatibility that in the past years have caused so many troubles
to the EC and its commercial partners in the WTO arena, on the other hand they
will raise new problems. In particular, it is very unlikely that the new ACP-EC
partnership will succeed in enhancing regional integration within the ACP group
of States as an instrument of economic development.
The analysis of the Cotonou Partnership Agreement, which clearly aims at
securing the ACP-EC trade regime to the WTO legal framework, offers the
occasion of asking another question: what happens when the discipline of
regional trade agreements in the WTO/GATT legal system interlaces with the
question of special and differential treatment, or, more generally, with
development issues? As we will see, the current GATT discipline of regional
trade agreements does not contemplate special and differential treatment
provisions for developing countries whereas they enter a customs union or a free
trade area with developed countries. We will therefore offer a synthetic review
and a provisional assessment of the principal proposals for the inclusion in the
GATT of special and differential treatment in “North-South” regional
agreements.
7
8
CHAPTER I
REGIONALISM IN THE WTO LEGAL SYSTEM
1. Regionalism in international trade law : definition and historical
evolutions
As anticipated in the introduction, one of the objectives of the present work is to
assess the main legal issues related to regionalism in the WTO system, focusing
in particular on the case of the relationship between the European Community7
and the group of Africa, Caribbean and Pacific countries. This chapter will
therefore deal with the main theoretical issues raised by the phenomenon under
examination, in order to provide us with the analytical tools needed to proceed
with an in-depth analysis of the EC-ACP trade relationship.
As a starting point, we need to come to a clear and understandable definition of
what it is actually meant here by the word “regionalism”.
The term might indeed result misleading; in fact, as we will see in the next
paragraph, GATT Article XXIV does not discipline “regionalism” as such:
instead, it makes reference to “customs unions”/“customs territories” and to “free
trade areas”.
Thus, when talking about regionalism in the GATT/WTO system, we refer to
such preferential schemes, which deviate from the principle of non-
discrimination, and we will indiscriminately make use of terms such as
7
We have chosen, for what concerns the scope of this dissertation, to make reference to the “European
Community” (EC) rather than to the “European Union” (EU) in the light of the fact that the EC (the EU’s
“first pillar” as first provided for by the Maastricht Treaty) and not the EU, is, together with its Member
States, a Contracting Party of the WTO agreements. As regards the years preceding the entry into force of
the Maastricht Treaty, we will resort to the original denomination, “European Economic
Community” (EEC).
9
“preferential schemes”, “regional integration arrangements”, “regional trade
agreements” and so on.
As Srinivasan notes, the majority of these schemes involve countries that are
close geographically, and, in this sense, “regional integration” is an appropriate
term to describe them8. The use of this expression is also well-established in the
WTO context, as exemplified by the WTO General Council’s Decision creating a
Committee for Regional Trade Agreements9. In fact, the text of the Decision
specifies that “the term ‘agreements’ (…) refers to all bilateral, regional, and
plurilateral trade agreements of a preferential nature”.
Notably, preferential trade agreements may aim at realizing different stages of
integration: the first step towards regional integration is the institution of a Free
Trade Area (FTA), meaning that all tariff barriers to trade are eliminated among
the member states, each of which can maintain its tariff schemes as for trade with
third countries. Free Trade Agreements are extremely diffused, and account for the
90% of the agreements concluded under GATT Article XXIV, GATS Article V
and the Enabling Clause .
The second stage is the creation of a Customs Union (CU): all tariff barriers are
eliminated among members, and a common external tariff is introduced for trade
with third countries. CUs account for approximately the 10% of the total regional
agreements signed within the WTO legal framework.
Proceeding with our brief analysis of the various existing forms of regional
integration, a Common Market not only brings tariffs among members down,
establishing a common external tariff, but also allows the free circulation of
persons and capitals across national borders. Finally, an Economic Union is a
Common Market also entailing fiscal and monetary harmonization. As in the case
of the European Union, an Economic Union might be the prelude to a genuine
political union.
8
T.N. Srinivasan, Regionalism and the WTO: Is Non-discrimination Passé? In Anne O. Krueger (edited
by) The WTO as an International Organisation, Chicago: University of Chicago Press (1998), p. 333
9
COMMITTEE ON REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS, Decision of 6 February 1996, WT/L/127.
The role of the Committee will be examined more in detail in par. 2.2 of this chapter.
10
Regionalism, in the meaning we just outlined, has become, over time, a major
feature of the multilateral trading system. We do not aim to enter the debate on
whether the trend towards regional economic integration is likely to undermine
multilateralism in world trade, rather than enhance it10 : we shall confine
ourselves to taking note of the fact that, since the 1980s, “the emphasis of the
world trading regime has shifted from one in which trade relations between
nations were almost entirely multilateral to one in which the open multilateral
system coexists with a series of preferential arrangements”11.
According to the last report of the Committee on Regional Trade Agreements, as
of 1 November 2007, 385 regional trade agreements have been notified to the
GATT or WTO, 197 of which are currently in force. Of the agreements in force,
125 were notified under GATT Article XXIV; 22 under the Enabling Clause,
and 50 under GATS Article V12. As Chart 1 clearly shows, the phenomenon has
dramatically increased in the years following the conclusion of the Uruguay
Round, and the positive trend is likely to continue.
This could indeed reflect the view that regional trade agreements are thought to
be an acceptable “second best” option for liberalizing trade, especially when long
and uncertain negotiations are in progress, as happened in the years that
preceded the Uruguay Round and as it is happening today, with the Doha Round
of negotiations still at a stalemate and a rising wave of “new protectionism”
undermining the faith in the multilateral trading system.
It is important to recall that, in the first years following the entry into force of
GATT, most of the preferential trade agreements were truly regional, involving
10
For a comprehensive account of such a debate, see, among the others, Jagdish Bhagwati; Arvind
Panagariya, - The Theory of Preferential Trade Agreements: Historical Evolution and Current Trends,
The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundredth and Eighth
Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association San Francisco, CA, January 5-7, 1996. (May,
1996), pp. 82-87 or Paul Krugman, Regionalism versus Multilateralism: Analytical Notes, in Jaime De
Melo and Arvind Pangariya (ed. by) New Dimensions in Regional Integration, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 58-84
11
Anne O. Krueger, “Are Preferential Trading Arrangements Trade-Liberalizing or Protectionist?” in The
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 13, No. 4. (Autumn, 1999), p.109.
12
Report (2007) of the Committee on Regional Trade Agreements to the General Council, 3 December
2007 , Doc. WT/REG/18, par. 4
11
countries which were geographically contiguous (i.e. as in the case of the
European Coal and Steel Community, or of the European Free Trade
Agreement). In more recent years, intra-regional preferential agreements
proliferated, also aiming at integrating countries which are very heterogeneous
as for geographic situation and level of economic development.
Chart 1 Regional trade agreements notified to the GATT/WTO (1948-2007), including inactive regional trade
agreements, by year of entry into force.
Source: WTO secretariat, http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/region_e/regfac_e.htm
In any case, regionalism, in a broad sense, is not new as a phenomenon, dating
back at least to the 19th century (i.e. the German Zollverein formed in 1834).
However, the focus here will be on regional trade agreements created after World
War II, in particular after the failure of the International Trade Organization.
In the period considered, regionalism has constantly remained a major feature of
the international trading system, though developing, as many scholars noted,
through several “waves” of diverse intensity, the first of which coincided with the
creation of the European Economic Community in 1957 and of the European Free
Trade Area in 1960. In this phase, regionalism also interested the newly
12